Legal Law

Information feedback loops in stock markets, investments, innovation and mathematical trends

It seems that no matter how complex our civilization and society become, we humans are capable of coping with ever-changing dynamics, finding reason in what appears to be chaos, and creating order out of what appears to be random. We go through our lives making observations, one after another, trying to find meaning; sometimes we are capable, sometimes we are not, and sometimes we think we see patterns that may or may not be. Our intuitive minds try to rhyme with reason, but in the end, without empirical evidence, much of our theories behind how and why things work or don’t work in a certain way cannot be proved or disproved.

I’d like to discuss with you an interesting piece of evidence discovered by a Wharton Business School professor that sheds some light on information flows, stock prices, and corporate decision making, and then ask you, the reader , some questions about how we could get more information about the things that happen around us, things that we observe in our society, civilization, economy and business world every day. Okay, so let’s talk, okay?

On April 5, 2017, Knowledge @ Wharton Podcast published an interesting article titled: “How the Stock Market Affects Corporate Decision Making” and interviewed Wharton Finance Professor Itay Goldstein who discussed evidence of a feedback loop. between the amount of information and the stock market. and corporate decision making. The professor had written an article with two other professors, James Dow and Alexander Guembel, in October 2011 entitled: “Incentives for the production of information in markets where prices affect real investment”.

In the paper, he noted that there is an information amplification effect when investing in a stock or merging based on the amount of information produced. Producers of market information; investment banks, consulting firms, independent industry consultants, and financial newsletters, newspapers, and I guess even TV segments on Bloomberg News, FOX Business News, and CNBC, as well as financial blogging platforms like Seeking Alpha.

The paper stated that when a company decides to embark on a merger acquisition spree or announces a potential investment, there is an immediate surge in information from multiple sources, internally within the merger acquisition firm, participating M&A investment banks , industry consulting firms, target company, regulators anticipating a move in the sector, competitors who may want to avoid the merger, etc. We all know intrinsically that this is the case when we read and watch the financial news, however, this document presents real data and shows empirical evidence of this fact.

This causes a feeding frenzy from small and large investors alike to trade on the now abundant information available, where before they had not considered it and there was no real important information to speak of. In the podcast, Professor Itay Goldstein points out that a feedback loop is created as the sector becomes more informed, leading to more trading, a bias to the upside, leading to more reporting and more information for investors. He also pointed out that people generally trade on positive information rather than negative information. Negative information would make investors stay away, positive information gives incentives for a potential profit. When consulted, the professor also pointed out the opposite, that when information decreases, investment in the sector also decreases.

Well, this was the essence of the podcast and the research work. Now, I would like to take this conversation and speculate that these truths also relate to new technologies and innovative sectors, and recent examples could be; 3D printing, commercial drones, augmented reality headsets, wristwatch computing, etc.

We are all familiar with the “Hype Curve” when it meets the “Innovation Diffusion Curve” where early hype drives investment, but is unsustainable due to the fact that it is a new technology that cannot yet deliver on the exaggeration of expectations. So it goes off like a rocket and then falls back to earth, only to find a balance point of reality, where the technology meets the expectations and the new innovation is ready to start maturing and then returns to life. go up and grow like a normal. the new innovation should.

With this known, and the empirical evidence of Itay Goldstein, et. al., paper, it would appear that “information flow” or lack thereof is the driving factor where PR, information, and hype do not accelerate along with the trajectory of the “hype curve” model. This makes sense because startups don’t necessarily continue to advertise or advertise as aggressively once they’ve secured the first rounds of venture funding or have enough capital to play with to achieve their temporary future goals for R&D of the new technology. However, I would suggest that these companies increase their PR (perhaps logarithmically) and provide information more abundantly and frequently to avoid an early drop in interest or depletion of the initial investment.

Another way to use this knowledge, which may require further research, would be to find the “optimal information flow” needed to achieve investment for new start-ups in the sector without pushing the “hype curve” too high and causing a market crash. . sector or with the potential new product of a particular company. Since an inherent feedback loop is now known, it would make sense to control it to optimize longer-term and stable growth when bringing innovative new products to market, facilitating investment planning and cash flows.

Mathematically speaking, finding the optimal information flow rate is possible and companies, investment banks with that knowledge could remove uncertainty and risk from the equation and thus encourage innovation with more predictable returns, perhaps time even staying just a few steps ahead of market imitators and competitors.

More questions for future research:

1.) Can we control investment information flows in emerging markets to avoid boom and bust cycles?

2.) Can central banks use mathematical algorithms to control information flows to stabilize growth?

3.) Can we reduce information flows that collaborate at ‘industry association levels’ as milestones as investments are made to protect the bottom of the curve?

4.) Can we program AI decision matrix systems into such equations to help executives sustain long-term corporate growth?

5.) Are there information ‘burst’ flow algorithms that align with these discovered correlations with investment and information?

6.) Can we improve derivatives trading software to recognize and exploit information investment feedback loops?

7.) Can we better track political races through information flow voting models? After all, voting with your investment dollar is a lot like voting for a candidate and the future.

8.) Can we use mathematical “trend” models of social networks as a basis for predictions of the trajectory of the course of investment in information?

What I would like you to do is think about all this, and see if you see, what do I see here?

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *